cover image: Understanding and Misunderstanding Randomized Controlled Trials

20.500.12592/743dvs

Understanding and Misunderstanding Randomized Controlled Trials

1 Sep 2016

RCTs would be more useful if there were more realistic expectations of them and if their pitfalls were better recognized. For example, and contrary to many claims in the applied literature, randomization does not equalize everything but the treatment across treatments and controls, it does not automatically deliver a precise estimate of the average treatment effect (ATE), and it does not relieve us of the need to think about (observed or unobserved) confounders. Estimates apply to the trial sample only, sometimes a convenience sample, and usually selected; justification is required to extend them to other groups, including any population to which the trial sample belongs. Demanding “external validity” is unhelpful because it expects too much of an RCT while undervaluing its contribution. Statistical inference on ATEs involves hazards that are not always recognized. RCTs do indeed require minimal assumptions and can operate with little prior knowledge. This is an advantage when persuading distrustful audiences, but it is a disadvantage for cumulative scientific progress, where prior knowledge should be built upon and not discarded. RCTs can play a role in building scientific knowledge and useful predictions but they can only do so as part of a cumulative program, combining with other methods, including conceptual and theoretical development, to discover not “what works,” but “why things work”.
econometrics experimental design health economics health care development economics estimation methods labor studies development and growth economics of aging

Authors

Angus Deaton, Nancy Cartwright

Acknowledgements & Disclosure
We acknowledge helpful discussions with many people over the several years this paper has been in preparation. We would particularly like to note comments from seminar participants at Princeton, Columbia, and Chicago, the CHESS research group at Durham, as well as discussions with Orley Ashenfelter, Anne Case, Nick Cowen, Hank Farber, Jim Heckman, Bo Honoré, Chuck Manski, and Julian Reiss. Ulrich Mueller had a major influence on shaping Section 1. We have benefited from generous comments on an earlier version by Christopher Adams, Tim Besley, Chris Blattman, Sylvain Chassang, Jishnu Das, Jean Drèze, William Easterly, Jonathan Fuller, Lars Hansen, Jeff Hammer, Glenn Harrison, Macartan Humphreys, Michal Kolesár, Helen Milner, Tamlyn Munslow, Suresh Naidu, Lant Pritchett, Dani Rodrik, Burt Singer, Richard Williams, Richard Zeckhauser, and Steve Ziliak. Cartwright’s research for this paper has received funding from the European Research Council (ERC) under the European Union’s Horizon 2020 research and innovation program (grant agreement No 667526 K4U), the Spencer Foundation, and the National Science Foundation (award 1632471). Deaton acknowledges financial support from the National Institute on Aging through the National Bureau of Economic Research, Grants 5R01AG040629-02 and P01AG05842-14 and through Princeton University’s Roybal Center, Grant P30 AG024928. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
DOI
http://dx.doi.org/10.3386/w22595
Published in
United States of America

Related Topics

All