cover image: Taxing Top Wealth: Migration Responses and their Aggregate Economic Implications

20.500.12592/612js6k

Taxing Top Wealth: Migration Responses and their Aggregate Economic Implications

16 Feb 2024

Using administrative data on wealth, firm ownership structure, and migration in Sweden and Denmark, we document international migration patterns among the very wealthy, their impact on the economy, and how they respond to wealth taxation. We show that more than 20% of taxpayers liable to pay wealth tax are business-owners, and that the employment, investments, and value-added of these businesses are negatively affected when their owner migrates out of the country. Exploiting three large reforms, we then isolate the causal effect of wealth taxation on the international location choices of the wealthy. We find significant effects on out-migration flows from increases in the effective wealth tax. But, we also document that the overall level of these migration flows is remarkably small, with annual net-migration rates below .01%. As a result, we find that the aggregate economic effects of tax-induced migration are modest in Scandinavia: a one percentage point increase in the average wealth tax rate on the top 2% decreases the stock of wealthy taxpayers by at most 2% in the long run, and lead to a reduction of at most .03% in aggregate employment and at most .1% in aggregate value- added. Hence, our results suggest that trickle-down effects of tax-induced migration by the wealthy do exist, but that they are quantitatively small.
taxation industrial organization macroeconomics corporate finance microeconomics public economics firm behavior labor studies productivity, innovation, and entrepreneurship consumption and investment market structure and distribution

Authors

Katrine Jakobsen, Henrik Kleven, Jonas Kolsrud, Camille Landais, Mathilde Muñoz

Acknowledgements & Disclosure
We are grateful to numerous seminar and conference participants for helpful comments and reactions. We thank Thomas Mikaelsen, Lukas Rodrian, Quirin Von Blomberg, Nicolas Grimprel and Rebecca Cambrini for outstanding research assistance. Munoz acknowledges financial support from the Stone Center at UC Berkeley. Camille Landais acknowledges financial support from the ERC Starting Grant #679704 and from the Philip Leverhulme Trust (Leverhulme Prize). Jakobsen also acknowledges financial support from the Independent Research Fund Denmark, Grant #0128-00007B. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
DOI
https://doi.org/10.3386/w32153
Published in
United States of America

Related Topics

All